Edit

Aggregate Demand and Secular Stagnation


Six years after the US economic contraction ended, the Federal Reserve has still not raised interest rates.  Inflation has not accelerated as so many predicted.  The economy is chugging along in an irregular fashion.  The US economy appears to have ground to a near halt in Q1 15. 

Lawrence Summers pulled together various elements that had identified this as the new normal.  He drew on the work of Alvin Hansen, who in the 1930s suggested a secular stagnation.  Just as Hansen sketched his argument on the eve of a new expansion in the US so too did Summers.  Summer's proposed his secular stagnation hypothesis in November 2013.  After a mostly weather-induced contraction in Q1 14, the US economy grew a 4.8% annualized clip between April and September, the fastest in over a decade. 

Summers identified the problem as one of chronic under-investment.   This leads to falling per capita incomes and stagnant demand.    This would generate politically unacceptably high levels of unemployment.  This has been avoided with the creation of serial asset bubbles  His solution is to boost public investment, through deficit financing. 

While the US sorely needs greater public investment, it is not clear that this is will address the problems Summers identifies.  The key issue is how to spur aggregate demand.  The public works programs of the New Deal, which Summers seems to hearken back to without citing them per se, was coupled with another set of policies that is all too often ignored in this discussions.  Over the last 30-40 years, private sector unions have been gutted.  The New Deal facilitated stronger unions. 

Few observers, including Summers, link the disparity of wealth and income to the weakness in aggregate demand.  And even fewer see the link between this condition and the weakness of precisely those organizations whose raison d'etre is reducing the disparity and boosting aggregate demand.  It was Samuel Gompers, the founder of the American Federation of Labor that defined his vision as getting workers "more now".  

Summer's deficit financed public investment does not address this key issue.  Here is what it means in hard numbers.  The National Employment Law Project  delved into the Bureau of Labor Statistics and found that whopping 42.4% of all employees in the US earn less than $15 an hour or $31k annually.   Yes, there are some young people and students in this mix, but nearly half (46.4%) are 35 or older.  

The 0.9% rise in March retail sales was the first increase in four months and the largest increase in a year.  Yet it was still a disappointment.   The component used for GDP calculations rose by 0.3%, but this was not sufficient to offset the decline recorded in January and February.  To the extent that Americans are shopping, and the personal consumption component of Q4 GDP rose by 4.4% at annualized rate the strongest since 2006, they are doing so without revolving debt (credit cards).  

Summers rightly argues that businesses today do not have the capital needs they had in the past.  Rather than takers from the capital markets, corporations with their huge cash holdings are now net providers.  Boosting aggregate demand may not happen simply because US roads, bridges, and ports are modernized,  the power grid is upgraded and the state-of-the-art networking capability is provided. All of these things may be desired in their own right.  However, the best way to boost aggregate demand is to ensure that a greater share of productivity gains go to wages rather than profits.     Stronger unions offer a non-statist way to overcome Summer's secular stagnation. 
Aggregate Demand and Secular Stagnation Aggregate Demand and Secular Stagnation Reviewed by Marc Chandler on April 14, 2015 Rating: 5
Powered by Blogger.